14.02 Quiz 2 CONFLICT Solutions
a. FALSE
This question is actually trickier than many realized. A recession in a foreign country is a fall
in Y*. This results in a drop in
exports for the domestic economy, which lowers domestic income, Y. But lower domestic income means lower
purchases of imports. The total effect
on net exports is not ambiguous, however.
If the import effect outweighed the export effect, then NX would rise,
but this would imply that Y also rises (the only change in the model is the
fall in Y*), contradicting the assumption that Y fell causing Q to fall. Thus the fall in Y* causes a decrease in
both Y and NX.
b. TRUE
An appreciation will cause an immediate increase in net exports. The Marshall-Lerner condition says that an
appreciation will cause net exports to fall, but this is only after both prices
(the exchange rate) and quantities (X and Q) have adjusted. In the very short run, quantities are fixed
so the fall in the exchange rate causes net exports to rise before they fall
since NX = X(E) - EQ(E).
c. TRUE
The domestic demand for goods is C + I + G, the demand for domestic
goods is C + I + G + NX. If NX = 0, or
the trade deficit is zero, these are equal.
d. FALSE
A depreciation of the currency is consistent with a fall in the
interest rate (the arbitrage equation is downward sloping). A monetary expansion would cause a decrease
in i, but it would also have the effect of increasing Y (as we move along the
IS curve). A fiscal contraction would
cause a decrease in i, but with a decrease in Y. A combination of these two policies, however, can lower the
interest rate, depreciating the currency, without changing Y. You cannot keep Y constant with just one of
the policy tools.
e. TRUE
Under perfect capital mobility, the interest parity condition must hold: i = i* + (E(e)-E)/E. Each of the variables on the right hand side is fixed or exogenous under fixed exchange rates, so the domestic interest rate is determined and the government is not free to choose it. Full credit may be given for arguing that, under a credible fixed exchange rate regime, the expected exchange rate is equal to the exchange rate so that the interest parity condition implies that the domestic interest rate is equal to the foreign interest rate. (You should have made the assumption of credible fixed exchange rates explicit if you made this argument.) Finally, it is not correct to assume that the country is the ‘lead country’ and hence it can set its interest rate and everyone else has to follow. This is because, first, one should not make unwarranted assumptions outside the model, and second, there does not have to be a ‘lead country’ (this might make sense if you’re considering the US in an exchange rate system with several Caribbean islands, but not if it’s a group of similarly sized economies).
f. TRUE
If the US dollar is expected to depreciate, then Ee>E. So the interest parity condition, i = i* +
(Ee-E)/E, then implies that i>i*. One could also argue that foreign investors in US bonds must be compensated
for the loss they will make on the currency side of their transactions with a
higher nominal interest rate.
g. TRUE
This question is about overshooting, which is covered in the
appendix to chapter 21. The increase in
the interest rate generated by a contractionary monetary policy will attract
investment to the domestic economy.
This causes an appreciation of the currency, i.e. a decrease in the
exchange rate. But this only tells you
the direction of the effect on the exchange rate, not the magnitude of the
effect. Arguing that if the exchange rate is higher for longer, more investment
will be attracted, so the effect is bigger is not acceptable. Rather, the magnitude of the effect is
determined by the arbitrage equation: the expected depreciation of the currency
in each year of the contraction must
be equal to the difference in domestic and foreign interest rates. So the current appreciation is equal to the
number of years the monetary expansion is expected to last times the difference
in interest rates. (To see this from
the arbitrage equation, consider that if
the exchange rate is expected to return to its long-run level at time
t+2, and the currency is going to depreciate by, say, 2% from t+1 to t+2, then
you expect the exchange rate to be 2% lower at time t+1 than the long-run
level, i.e. Ee(t+1) changes.
But then for the currency to depreciate 2% from t to t+1, the exchange
rate must now be (approximately) 4% lower at time t than its long-run
level.) A longer contraction will thus
result in a greater current appreciation.
See the text for the graphs and additional explanation.
Additionally, please note that a contraction is a sudden event: the
money supply is moved from one level to another quickly. The duration is the amount of time before
the money supply is returned to its pre-contraction level, not the amount of
time it takes to get to the lower level.
Note: “solving” this model for the closed economy (with the same numbers) gives a “negative” multiplier; doing this alone is not a complete answer to the question of the difference between the closed and open systems.
Note: if you answered with an IS curve that did not include E substituted in (i.e. holding E constant), and used this expression, you may also receive full credit. You must in this case, however, explicitly worry about “second order shifts” of the IS curve in the next exercises (G changing so IS moves, but then E changes which moves IS again, so that net effect is either larger because the IS moves in the same direction, or may be smaller, etc.)
For a monetary contraction, lower M implies higher interest rates for any level of output. The LM curve shifts in. Higher interest rates depress I and NX (moving along the IS curve), so we have lower Y, higher i and thus lower E (appreciation) eventually. Investment is lower, NX is unclear (Y effect vs. E effect).
QUESTION 3