Thursday,
April 19, 2001
5:00 - 7:00 p.m.
Bartos
Theater
MIT Media Lab
20 Ames Street
Abstract
Copyright
developed in the age of the printing press, and was designed
to fit well with the system of centralized copying imposed by
the printing press. But the copyright system does not fit well
with computer networks, and only Draconian punishments can enforce
it. Today the global corporations that profit from copyright
are attempting to increase their copyright powers, while suppressing
public access to technology so that they can retain control.
But if we seriously hope to serve the purpose for which copyright
was established in the US--to promote progress, for the benefit
of the public--what needs to be done is either to reduce copyright
powers or effectively eliminate them, depending on the kind
of work. Governments must now protect the public's right to
copy.
Speaker
Richard Stallman is the founder of the Free Software Foundation
and the GNU Project, launched in 1984 to develop the free operating
system called GNU ("GNU's
Not Unix"). In 1998, he received the Electronic Frontier
Foundation's Pioneer Award along with Linux inventor Linus Torvalds.
Stallman graduated from Harvard in 1974 with a B.A. in physics.
Summary
[The
following is an edited transcript of the conclusion of Richard
Stallmans talk. A transcript of the complete talk
including the question-and-answer session is also available.]
|
|
If
we look ahead to the time when the age of the computer networks
will have fully begun, when were past this transitional
stage, we can envision another way for authors to get money
for their work. Imagine that we have a digital cash
system that enables you to get money for your work.
Imagine that we have a digital cash system that enables
you to send somebody else money through the Internet; this
can be done in various ways using encryption, for instance. And
imagine that verbatim copying of all these aesthetic works
is permitted. But theyre written in such a way
that when you are playing one or reading one or watching
one, a box appears on the side of your screen that says,
Click here to send a dollar to the author, or
the musician or whatever. And it just sits there;
it doesnt get in your way; its on the side.
It doesnt interfere with you, but its there,
reminding you that its a good thing to support the
writers and the musicians.
|
So if you
love the work that youre reading or listening to, eventually
youre going to say, Why shouldnt I give these
people a dollar? Its only a dollar. Whats
that? I wont even miss it. And people
will start sending a dollar. The good thing about this
is that it makes copying the ally of the authors and musicians.
When somebody e-mails a friend a copy, that friend might send
a dollar, too. If you really love it, you might send a
dollar more than once and that dollar is more than theyre
going to get today if you buy the book or buy the CD because
they get a tiny fraction of the sale. The same publishers
that are demanding total power over the public in the name of
the authors and musicians are giving those authors and musicians
the shaft all the time.
I recommend you read Courtney Loves article in Salon
magazine, an article about pirates that plan to use musicians
work without paying them. These pirates are the record
companies that pay musicians 4% of the sales figures, on the
average. Of course, the very successful musicians have
more clout. They get more than 4% of their large sales
figures, which means that the great run of musicians who have
a record contract get less than 4% of their small sales figures.
Heres the way it works: The record company spends money
on publicity and they consider this expenditure as an advance
to the musicians, although the musicians never see it.
So nominally when you buy a CD, a certain fraction of that money
is going to the musicians, but really it isnt. Really,
its going to pay back the publicity expenses, and only
if the musicians are very successful do they ever see any of
that money.
The musicians, of course, sign their record contracts because
they hope theyre going to be one of those few who strike
it rich. So essentially a rolling lottery is being offered
to the musicians to tempt them. Although theyre
good at music, they may not be good at careful, logical reasoning
to see through this trap. So they sign and then probably
all they get is publicity. Well, why dont we give
them publicity in a different way, not through a system thats
based on restricting the public and a system of the industrial
complex that saddles us with lousy music thats easy to
sell. Instead, why not make the listeners natural
impulse to share the music they love the ally of the musicians?
If we have this box that appears in the player as a way to send
a dollar to the musicians, then the computer networks could
be the mechanism for giving the musicians this publicity, the
same publicity which is all they get from record contracts now.
We have to recognize that the existing copyright system does
a lousy job of supporting musicians, just as lousy as world
trade does of raising living standards in the Philippines and
China. You have these enterprise zones where everyone
works in a sweatshop and all of the products are made in sweatshops.
I knew that globalization was a very inefficient way of raising
living standards of people overseas. Say, an American
is getting paid $20 an hour to make something and you give that
job to a Mexican who is getting paid maybe six dollars a day,
what has happened here is that youve taken a large amount
of money away from an American worker, given a tiny fraction,
like a few percents, to a Mexican worker and given back the
rest to the company. So if your goal is to raise
the living standards of Mexican workers, this is a lousy way
to do it.Its interesting to see how the same phenomenon
is going on in the copyright industry, the same general idea.
In the name of these workers who certainly deserve something,
you propose measures that give them a tiny bit and really mainly
prop up the power of corporations to control our lives.
If youre trying to replace a very good system, you have
to work very hard to come up with a better alternative.
If you know that the present system is lousy, its not
so hard to find a better alternative; the standard of comparison
today is very low. We must always remember that when we
consider issues of copyright policy.
So I think Ive said most of what I want to say.
Id like to mention that tomorrow is Phone-In Sick Day
in Canada. Tomorrow is the beginning of a summit to finish
negotiating the free trade area of the Americas to try to extend
corporate power throughout additional countries, and a big protest
is being planned for Quebec. Weve seen extreme methods
being used to smash this protest. A lot of Americans are
being blocked from entering Canada through the border that theyre
supposed to be allowed to enter through at any time. On
the flimsiest of excuses, a wall has been built around the center
of Quebec to be used as a fortress to keep protesters out.
Weve seen a large number of different dirty tricks used
against public protest against these treaties. So whatever
democracy remains to us after government powers have been taken
away from democratically elected governors and given to businesses
and to unelected international bodies, whatever is left after
that may not survive the suppression of public protest against
it.
Transcript
[The
following is an edited transcript.]
DAVID THORBURN, moderator: Our
speaker today, Richard Stallman, is a legendary figure in the
computing world, and my experience in trying to find a respondent
to share the podium with him was instructive. One distinguished
MIT professor told me that Stallman needs to be understood as
a charismatic figure in a biblical parable a kind of
Old Testament anecdote-lesson. Imagine, he
said, a Moses or a Jeremiah better a Jeremiah. And
I said, Well, thats very admirable. That sounds
wonderful. It confirms my sense of the kind of contribution
he has made to the world. Then why are you reluctant to
share the podium with him? His answer: Like
Jeremiah or Moses, he would simply overwhelm me. I wont
appear on the same panel as him, but if you asked me to name
five people alive in the world who have truly helped us all,
Richard Stallman would be one of them.
RICHARD
STALLMAN: I should [begin by explaining why I have
refused to allow this Forum to be webcast], in case it
wasnt clear fully what the issue is: The software
they use for web broadcasting requires the user to download
certain software in order to receive the broadcast. That
software is not free software. Its available at
zero price but only as an executable, which is a mysterious
bunch of numbers.
What it does is secret. You cant study it; you cant
change it; and you certainly cant publish it in your own
modified version. And those are among the freedoms that
are essential in the definition of free software.
So if I
am to be an honest advocate for free software, I can hardly
go around giving speeches, then put pressure on people to use
non-free software. Id be undermining my own cause.
And if I dont show that I take my principles seriously,
I cant expect anybody else to take them seriously.
However, this speech is not about free software. After Id
been working on the free-software movement for several years
and people started using some of the pieces of the GNU operating
system, I began getting invited to give speeches [at which]
. . . people started asking me: Well, how
do the ideas about freedom for software users generalize to
other kinds of things?
And, of course, people asked silly questions like, Well,
should hardware be free? Should this microphone
be free? Well, what does that mean? Should
you be free to copy it and change it? Well, as for changing
it, if you buy the microphone, nobody is going to stop you from
changing it. And as for copying it, nobody has a microphone
copier. Outside of Star Trek, those things
dont exist. Maybe some day therell be nanotechnological
analyzers and assemblers, and it really will be possible to
copy a physical object, and then these issues of whether youre
free to do that will start being really important. Well
see agribusiness companies trying to stop people from copying
food, and that will become a major political issue, if that
technological capability will ever exist. I dont
know if it will; its just speculation at this point.
But for other kinds of information, you can raise the issue
because any kind of information that can be stored on a computer,
conceivably, can be copied and modified. So the ethical
issues of free software, the issues of a users right to
copy and modify software, are the same as such questions for
other kinds of published information. Now Im not
talking about private information, say, personal information,
which is never meant to be available to the public at all.
Im talking about the rights you should have if you get
copies of published things where theres no attempt to
keep them secret.
In order to explain my ideas on the subject, Id like to
review the history of the distribution of information and of
copyright. In the ancient world, books were written by
hand with a pen, and anybody who knew how to read and write
could copy a book about as efficiently as anybody else.
Now somebody who did it all day would probably learn to be somewhat
better at it, but there was not a tremendous difference.
And because the copies were made one at a time, there was no
great economy of scale. Making ten copies took ten times
as long as making one copy. There was also nothing forcing
centralization; a book could be copied anywhere.
Now because of this technology, because it didnt force
copies to be identical, there wasnt in the ancient world
the same total divide between copying a book and writing a book.
There are things in between that made sense. They did
understand the idea of an author. They knew, say, that
this play was written by Sophocles but in between writing a
book and copying a book, there were other useful things you
could do. For instance, you could copy a part of a book,
then write some new words, copy some more and write some new
words and on and on. This was called writing a commentary
-- that was a common thing to do and these commentaries
were appreciated.You could also copy a passage out of one book,
then write some other words, and copy a passage from another
book and write some more and so on, and this was making a compendium.
Compendia were also very useful. There are works that
are lost but parts of them survived when they were quoted into
other books that got to be more popular than the original.
Maybe they copied the most interesting parts, and so people
made a lot of copies of these, but they didnt bother copying
the original because it wasnt interesting enough.
Now as far as I can tell, there was no such thing as copyright
in the ancient world. Anyone who wanted to copy a book
could copy the book. Later on, the printing press was
developed and books started to be copied on the printing press.
Now the printing press was not just a quantitative improvement
in the ease of copying. It affected different kinds of
copying unevenly because it introduced an inherent economy of
scale. It was a lot of work to set the type and much less
work to make many identical copies of the page. So the
result was that copying books tended to become a centralized,
mass-production activity. Copies of any given book would
probably be made in only a few places.
It also meant that ordinary readers couldnt copy books
efficiently. Only if you had a printing press could you
do that. So it was an industrial activity.
Now for the first few centuries of printing, printed books did
not totally replace hand-copying. Hand-copied books were
still made, sometimes by rich people and sometimes by poor people.
The rich people did this to get an especially beautiful copy
that would show how rich they were, and poor people did it because
maybe they didnt have enough money to buy a printed copy
but they had the time to copy a book by hand. As the song
says, Time aint money when all you got is time.
So hand-copying was still done to some extent. I think
it was in the 1800s that printing actually got to be cheap enough
that even poor people could afford printed books if they were
literate.Now copyright was developed along with the use of the
printing press and given the technology of the printing press,
it had the effect of an industrial regulation. It didnt
restrict what readers could do; it restricted what publishers
and authors could do. Copyright in England was initially
a form of censorship. You had to get government permission
to publish the book. But the idea has changed. By
the time of the U.S. Constitution, people came to a different
idea of the purpose of copyright, and I think that that idea
was accepted in England as well.
For the U.S. Constitution it was proposed that authors should
be entitled to a copyright, a monopoly on copying their books.
This proposal was rejected. Instead, a crucially different
proposal was adopted which is that, for the sake of promoting
progress, Congress could optionally establish a copyright system
that would create these monopolies. So the monopolies,
according to the U.S. Constitution, do not exist for the sake
of those who own them; they exist for the sake of promoting
the progress of science. The monopolies are handed out
to authors as a way of modifying their behavior to get them
to do something that serves the public.
So the goal is more written and published books which other
people can then read. And this is believed to contribute
to increased literary activity, increased writing about science
and other fields, and society then learns through this.
Thats the purpose to be served. The creation
of private monopolies was a means to an end only, and the end
is a public end.
Now copyright in the age of the printing press was fairly painless
because it was an industrial regulation. It restricted
only the activities of publishers and authors. Well, in
some strict sense, the poor people who copied books by hand
may have been infringing copyright, too. But nobody ever
tried to enforce copyright against them because it was understood
as an industrial regulation.Copyright in the age of the printing
press was also easy to enforce because it had to be enforced
only where there was a publisher, and publishers, by their nature,
make themselves known. If youre trying to sell books,
youve got to tell people where to come to buy them.
You dont have to go into everybodys house to enforce
copyright.
And, finally, copyright may have been a beneficial system in
that context. Copyright in the U.S. is considered by legal
scholars as a trade, a bargain between the public and authors.
The public trades away some of its natural rights to make copies,
and in exchange gets the benefit of more books being written
and published.
Now, is this an advantageous trade? Well, when the general
public cant make copies because they can only be efficiently
made on printing presses and most people dont own
printing presses the result is that the general public
is trading away a freedom it is unable to exercise, a freedom
that is of no practical value. So if you have something
that is a byproduct of your life and its useless and you
have the opportunity to exchange it for something else of any
value, youre gaining. So thats why copyright
may have been an advantageous trade for the public in that time.
But the context is changing, and that has to change our ethical
evaluation of copyright. Now the basic principles of ethics
are not changed by advances in technology; theyre too
fundamental to be touched by such contingencies. But our
decision about any specific question is a matter of the consequences
of the alternatives available, and the consequences of a given
choice may change when the context changes. That is what
is happening in the area of copyright law because the age of
the printing press is coming to an end, giving way gradually
to the age of the computer networks.Computer networks and digital
information technology are bringing us back to a world more
like the ancient world where anyone who can read and use the
information can also copy it and can make copies about as easily
as anyone else could make them. They are perfect copies
and theyre just as good as the copies anyone else could
make. So the centralization and economy of scale introduced
by the printing press and similar technologies is going away.
And this changing context changes the way copyright law works.
You see, copyright law no longer acts as an industrial regulation;
it is now a Draconian restriction on a general public.
It used to be a restriction on publishers for the sake of authors.
Now, for practical purposes, its a restriction on a public
for the sake of publishers. Copyright used to be fairly
painless and uncontroversial. It didnt restrict
the general public. Now thats not true. If
you have a computer, the publishers consider restricting you
to be their highest priority. Copyright was easy to enforce
because it was a restriction only on publishers who were easy
to find and what they published was easy to see. Now the
copyright is a restriction on each and everyone of you.
To enforce it requires surveillance an intrusion
and harsh punishments, and we are seeing these being enacted
into law in the U.S. and other countries.
And copyright used to be, arguably, an advantageous trade for
the public to make because the public was trading away freedoms
it couldnt exercise. Well, now it can exercise these
freedoms. What do you do if you have been producing a
byproduct which was of no use to you and you were in the habit
of trading it away and then, all of a sudden, you discover a
use for it? You can actually consume it, use it.
What do you do? You dont trade at all; you keep
some. And thats what the public would naturally
want to do. Thats what the public does whenever
its given a chance to voice its preference; it keeps some
of this freedom and exercises it. Napster is a big example
of that, the public deciding to exercise the freedom to copy
instead of giving it up. So the natural thing for us to
do to make copyright law fit todays circumstances is to
reduce the amount of copyright power that copyright owners get,
to reduce the amount of restriction that they place on the public
and to increase the freedom that the public retains. But
this is not what the publishers want to do. What they
want to do is exactly the opposite. They wish to increase
copyright powers to the point where they can remain firmly in
control of all use of information. This has led to laws
that have given an unprecedented increase in the powers of copyright.
Freedoms that the public used to have in the age of the printing
press are being taken away.
For instance, lets look at e-books. Theres
a tremendous amount of hype about e-books; you can hardly avoid
it. I took a flight in Brazil and in the in-flight magazine,
there was an article saying that maybe it would take 10 or 20
years before we all switched to e-books. Clearly, this
kind of campaign comes from somebody paying for it. Now
why are they doing that? I think I know. The reason
is that e-books are the opportunity to take away some of the
residual freedoms that readers of printed books have always
had and still have the freedom, for instance, to lend
a book to your friend or borrow it from the public library or
sell a copy to a used bookstore or buy a copy anonymously, without
putting a record in the database of who bought that particular
book. And maybe even the right to read it twice.
These are freedoms that the publishers would like to take away,
but they cant do this for printed books because that would
be too obvious a power-grab and would raise an outcry. So they
have found an indirect strategy: First, they obtain the
legislation to take away these freedoms for e-books when there
are no e-books; so theres no controversy. There
are no pre-existing users of e-books who are accustomed to their
freedoms and will defend them. That they obtained with
the Digital Millennium Copyright Act in 1998. Then they
introduce e-books and gradually get everybody to switch from
printed books to e-books and eventually the result is, readers
have lost these freedoms without ever having an instant when
those freedoms were being taken away and when they might have
fought back to retain them.We see at the same time efforts to
take away peoples freedom in using other kinds of published
works. For instance, movies that are on DVDs are published
in an encrypted format that used to be secret it was
meant to be secret and the only way the movie companies
would tell you the format, so that you could make a DVD player,
was if you signed a contract to build certain restrictions into
the player, with the result that the public would be stopped
even from fully exercising their legal rights. Then a
few clever programmers in Europe figured out the format of DVDs
and they wrote a free software package that would read a DVD.
This made it possible to use free software on top of the GNU
Plus Linux operating system to watch the DVD that you had bought,
which is a perfectly legitimate thing to do. You ought
to be able to do that with free software.
But the movie companies objected and they went to court.
You see, the movie companies used to make a lot of films where
there was a mad scientist and somebody was saying, But,
Doctor, there are some things Man was not meant to know.
They must have watched their own films too much because they
came to believe that the format of DVDs is something that Man
was not meant to know. And they obtained a ruling for
total censorship of the software for playing DVDs. Even
making a link to a site where this information is legally available
outside the U.S. has been prohibited. An appeal has been
made against this ruling. I signed a friend-of-the-court
brief in that appeal, Im proud to say, although Im
playing a fairly small role in that particular battle.
The U.S. government intervened directly on the other side.
This is not surprising when you consider why the Digital Millennium
Copyright Act was passed in the first place. The reason
is the campaign finance system that we have in the U.S., which
is essentially legalized bribery where the candidates are bought
by business before they even get elected. And, of course,
they know who their master is they know whom theyre
working for and they pass the laws to give business more
power.
What will happen with that particular battle, we dont
know. But meanwhile Australia has passed a similar law
and Europe is almost finished adopting one; so the plan is to
leave no place on earth where this information can be made available
to people. But the U.S. remains the world leader in trying
to stop the public from distributing information thats
been published.The U.S. though is not the first country to make
a priority of this. The Soviet Union treated it as very
important. There this unauthorized copying and re-distribution
was known as Samizdat and to stamp it out, they developed a
series of methods: First, guards watching every piece
of copying equipment to check what people were copying to prevent
forbidden copying. Second, harsh punishments for anyone
caught doing forbidden copying. You could sent to Siberia.
Third, soliciting informers, asking everyone to rat on their
neighbors and co-workers to the information police. Fourth,
collective responsibility You! Youre going
to watch that group! If I catch any of them doing forbidden
copying, you are going to prison. So watch them hard.
And, fifth, propaganda, starting in childhood to convince everyone
that only a horrible enemy of the people would ever do this
forbidden copying.
The U.S. is using all of these measures now. First, guards
watching copying equipment. Well, in copy stores, they
have human guards to check what you copy. But human guards
to watch what you copy in your computer would be too expensive;
human labor is too expensive. So they have robot guards.
Thats the purpose of the Digital Millennium Copyright
Act. This software goes in your computer; its the
only way you can access certain data and it stops you from copying.
Theres a plan now to introduce this software into every
hard disk, so that there could be files on your hard disk that
you cant even access except by getting permission from
some network server to access the file. And to bypass
this software or even tell other people how to bypass it is
a crime.
Second, harsh punishments. A few years ago, if you made
copies of something and handed them out to your friends just
to be helpful, this was not a crime; it had never been a crime
in the U.S. Then they made it a felony, so you could be
put in prisons for years for sharing with your neighbor.
Third, informers. Well, you may have seen the ads on TV,
the ads in the Boston subways asking people to rat on their
co-workers to the information police, which officially is called
the Software Publishers Association.And fourth, collective responsibility.
In the U.S., this has been done by conscripting Internet service
providers, making them legally responsible for everything their
customers post. The only way they can avoid always being
held responsible is if they have an invariable procedure to
disconnect or remove the information within two weeks after
a complaint. Just a few days ago, I heard that a clever
protest site criticizing City Bank for some of its nasty policies
was disconnected in this way. Nowadays, you dont
even get your day in court; your site just gets unplugged.
And, finally, propaganda, starting in childhood. Thats
what the word pirate is used for. If youll
think back a few years, the term pirate was formerly
applied to publishers that didnt pay the author.
But now its been turned completely around. Its
now applied to members of the public who escape from the control
of the publisher. Its being used to convince people
that only a nasty enemy of the people would ever do this forbidden
copying. It says that sharing with your neighbor
is the moral equivalent of attacking a ship. I hope
that you dont agree with that and if you dont, I
hope you will refuse to use the word in that way.
So the publishers are purchasing laws to give themselves more
power. In addition, theyre also extending the length
of time the copyright lasts. The U.S. Constitution says
that copyright must last for a limited time, but the publishers
want copyright to last forever. However, getting a constitutional
amendment would be rather difficult, so they found an easier
way that achieves the same result. Every 20 years they
retroactively extend copyright by 20 years. So the result
is, at any given time, copyright nominally lasts for a certain
period and any given copyright will nominally expire some day.
But that expiration will never be reached because every copyright
will be extended by 20 years every 20 years; thus no work will
ever go into the public domain again. This has been called
perpetual copyright on the installment plan.
The law in 1998 that extended copyright by 20 years is known
as the Mickey Mouse Copyright Extension Act because
one of the main sponsors of this law was Disney. Disney
realized that the copyright on Mickey Mouse was going to expire,
and they dont want that to ever happen because they make
a lot of money from that copyright.Now the original title of
this talk was supposed to be Copyright and Globalization.
If you look at globalization, what you see is that its
carried out by a number of policies which are done in the name
of economic efficiency or so-called free-trade treaties, which
really are designed to give business power over laws and policies.
Theyre not really about free trade. Theyre
about a transfer of power: removing the power to decide
laws from the citizens of any country who might conceivably
consider their own interests and giving that power to businesses
who will not consider the interests of those citizens.
Democracy is the problem in their view, and these treaties are
designed to put an end to the problem. For instance, NAFTA
actually contains provisions, I believe, allowing companies
to sue another government to get rid of a law that they believe
is interfering with their profits in the other country.
So foreign companies have more power than citizens of the country.
There are attempts being made to extend this beyond NAFTA.
For instance, this is one of the goals of the so-called free
trade area of the Americas, to extend this principle to all
the countries in South America and the Caribbean as well, and
the multilateral agreement on investment was intended to spread
it to the whole world.
One thing weve seen in the 90s is that these treaties
begin to impose copyright throughout the world, and in more
powerful and restrictive ways. These treaties are not
free-trade treaties. Theyre actually corporate-controlled
trade treaties being used to give corporations control over
world trade, in order to eliminate free trade.When the U.S.
was a developing country in the 1800s, the U.S. did not recognize
foreign copyrights. This was a decision made carefully,
and it was an intelligent decision. It was acknowledged
that for the U.S. to recognize foreign copyrights would just
be disadvantageous, that it would suck money out and wouldnt
do much good.
The same logic would apply today to developing countries but
the U.S. has sufficient power to force them to go against their
interests. Actually, its a mistake to speak of the
interests of countries in this context. In fact, Im
sure that most of you have heard about the fallacy of trying
to judge the public interest by adding up everybodys wealth.
If working Americans lost $1 billion and Bill Gates gained $2
billion, would Americans generally be better off? Would
this be good for America? Or if you look only at the total,
it looks like its good. However, this example really
shows that the total is the wrong way to judge because Bill
Gates really doesnt need another $2 billion, but the loss
of the $1 billion by other people who dont have as much
to start with might be painful. Well, in a discussion
about any of these trade treaties, when you hear people talk
about the interests of this country or that country, what theyre
doing, within each country, is adding up everybodys income.
The rich people and the poor people are being added up.
So its actually an excuse to apply that same fallacy to
get you to ignore the effect on the distribution of wealth within
the country and whether the treaty is going to make that more
uneven, as it has done in the U.S.
So its really not the U.S. interest that is being served
by enforcing copyright around the world. Its the
interests of certain business owners, many of whom are in the
U.S. and some of whom are in other countries. It doesnt,
in any sense, serve the public interest.
But what would make sense to do? If we believe in the
goal of copyright stated, for instance in the U.S. Constitution,
the goal of promoting progress, what would be intelligent policies
to use in the age of the computer network? Clearly, instead
of increasing copyright powers, we have to pull them back so
as to give the general public a certain domain of freedom where
they can make use of the benefits of digital technology, make
use of their computer networks. But how far should that
go? Thats an interesting question because I dont
think we should necessarily abolish copyright totally.
The idea of trading some freedoms for more progress might still
be an advantageous trade at a certain level, even if traditional
copyright gives up too much freedom. But in order to think
about this intelligently, the first thing we have to recognize
is, theres no reason to make it totally uniform.
Theres no reason to insist on making the same deal for
all kinds of work. In fact, that already isnt the
case because there are a lot of exceptions for music.
Music is treated very differently under copyright law.
But the arbitrary insistence on uniformity is used by the publishers
in a certain clever way. They pick some peculiar special
case and they make an argument that, in that special case, it
would be advantageous to have this much copyright. And
then they say that for uniformitys sake, there has to
be this much copyright for everything. So, of course,
they pick the special case where they can make the strongest
argument, even if its a rather rare special case and not
really very important overall.
But maybe we should have that much copyright for that particular
special case. We dont have to pay the same price
for everything we buy. A thousand dollars for a new car
might be a very good deal. A thousand dollars for a container
of milk is a horrible deal. You wouldnt pay the
special price for everything you buy in other areas of life.
Why do it here?
So we need to look at different kinds of works, and Id
like to propose a way of doing this.
This includes recipes, computer programs, manuals and textbooks,
reference works like dictionaries and encyclopedias. For
all these functional works, I believe that the issues are basically
the same as they are for software and the same conclusions apply.
People should have the freedom even to publish a modified version
because its very useful to modify functional works.
Peoples needs are not all the same. If I wrote this
work to do the job I think needs doing, your idea as a job you
want to do may be somewhat different. So you want to modify
this work to do whats good for you. At that point,
there may be other people who have similar needs to yours, and
your modified version might be good for them. Everybody
who cooks knows this and has known this for hundreds of years.
Its normal to make copies of recipes and hand them out
to other people, and its also normal to change a recipe.
If you change the recipe and cook it for your friends and they
like eating it, they might ask you, Could I have the recipe?
Then maybe youll write down your version and give them
copies. That is exactly the same thing that we much later
started doing in the free-software community.So thats
one class of work. The second class of work is works
whose purpose is to say what certain people think. Talking
about those people is their purpose. This includes, say,
memoirs, essays of opinion, scientific papers, offers to buy
and sell, catalogues of goods for sale. The whole point
of those works is that they tell you what somebody thinks or
what somebody saw or what somebody believes. To modify
them is to misrepresent the authors; so modifying these works
is not a socially useful activity. And so verbatim
copying is the only thing that people really need to be allowed
to do.
The next question is: Should people have the right to
do commercial verbatim copying? Or is non-commercial enough?
You see, these are two different activities we can distinguish,
so that we can consider the questions separately the
right to do non-commercial verbatim copying and the right to
do commercial verbatim copying. Well, it might be a good
compromise policy to have copyright cover commercial verbatim
copying but allow everyone the right to do non-commercial verbatim
copying. This way, the copyright on the commercial verbatim
copying, as well as on all modified versions only the
author could approve a modified version would still provide
the same revenue stream that it provides now to fund the writing
of these works, to whatever extent it does.
By allowing the non-commercial verbatim copying, it means the
copyright no longer has to intrude into everybodys home.
It becomes an industrial regulation again, easy to enforce and
painless, no longer requiring Draconian punishments and informers
for the sake of its enforcement. So we get most of the
benefit and avoid most of the horror of the current
system.The third category of works is aesthetic or entertaining
works, where the most important thing is just the sensation
of looking at the work. Now for these works, the issue
of modification is a very difficult one because on the one hand,
there is the idea that these works reflect the vision of an
artist and to change them is to mess up that vision. On
the other hand, you have the fact that there is the folk process,
where a sequence of people modifying a work can sometimes produce
a result that is extremely rich. Even when you have artists
producing the works, borrowing from previous works is often
very useful. Some of Shakespeares plays used a story
that was taken from some other play. If todays copyright
laws had been in effect back then, those plays would have been
illegal. So its a hard question what we should do
about publishing modified versions of an aesthetic or an artistic
work, and we might have to look for further subdivisions of
the category in order to solve this problem. For example,
maybe computer game scenarios should be treated one way; maybe
everybody should be free to publish modified versions of them.
But perhaps a novel should be treated differently; perhaps for
that, commercial publication should require an arrangement with
the original author.
Now if commercial publication of these aesthetic works is covered
by copyright, that will give most of the revenue stream that
exists today to support the authors and musicians, to the limited
extent that the present system supports them, because it does
a very bad job. So that might be a reasonable compromise,
just as in the case of the works which represent certain people.
If we look ahead to the time when the age of the computer networks
will have fully begun, when were past this transitional
stage, we can envision another way for the authors to get money
for their work. Imagine that we have a digital cash system
that enables you to get money for your work. Imagine that
we have a digital cash system that enables you to send somebody
else money through the Internet; this can be done in various
ways using encryption, for instance. And imagine that
verbatim copying of all these aesthetic works is permitted.
But theyre written in such a way that when you are playing
one or reading one or watching one, a box appears on the side
of your screen that says, Click here to send a dollar
to the author, or the musician or whatever. And
it just sits there; it doesnt get in your way; its
on the side. It doesnt interfere with you, but its
there, reminding you that its a good thing to support
the writers and the musicians.
So if you love the work that youre reading or listening
to, eventually youre going to say, Why shouldnt
I give these people a dollar? Its only a dollar.
Whats that? I wont even miss it.
And people will start sending a dollar. The good thing
about this is that it makes copying the ally of the authors
and musicians. When somebody e-mails a friend a copy,
that friend might send a dollar, too. If you really love
it, you might send a dollar more than once and that dollar is
more than theyre going to get today if you buy the book
or buy the CD because they get a tiny fraction of the sale.
The same publishers that are demanding total power over the
public in the name of the authors and musicians are giving those
authors and musicians the shaft all the time.
I recommend you read Courtney Loves article in Salon magazine,
an article about pirates that plan to use musicians work
without paying them. These pirates are the record companies
that pay musicians 4% of the sales figures, on the average.
Of course, the very successful musicians have more clout.
They get more than 4% of their large sales figures, which means
that the great run of musicians who have a record contract get
less than 4% of their small sales figures.
Heres the way it works: The record company spends money
on publicity and they consider this expenditure as an advance
to the musicians, although the musicians never see it.
So nominally when you buy a CD, a certain fraction of that money
is going to the musicians, but really it isnt. Really,
its going to pay back the publicity expenses, and only
if the musicians are very successful do they ever see any of
that money.
The musicians, of course, sign their record contracts because
they hope theyre going to be one of those few who strike
it rich. So essentially a rolling lottery is being offered
to the musicians to tempt them. Although theyre
good at music, they may not be good at careful, logical reasoning
to see through this trap. So they sign and then probably
all they get is publicity. Well, why dont we give
them publicity in a different way, not through a system thats
based on restricting the public and a system of the industrial
complex that saddles us with lousy music thats easy to
sell. Instead, why not make the listeners natural
impulse to share the music they love the ally of the musicians?
If we have this box that appears in the player as a way to send
a dollar to the musicians, then the computer networks could
be the mechanism for giving the musicians this publicity, the
same publicity which is all they get from record contracts now.We
have to recognize that the existing copyright system does a
lousy job of supporting musicians, just as lousy as world trade
does of raising living standards in the Philippines and China.
You have these enterprise zones where everyone works in a sweatshop
and all of the products are made in sweatshops. I knew
that globalization was a very inefficient way of raising living
standards of people overseas. Say, an American is getting
paid $20 an hour to make something and you give that job to
a Mexican who is getting paid maybe six dollars a day, what
has happened here is that youve taken a large amount of
money away from an American worker, given a tiny fraction, like
a few percents, to a Mexican worker and given back the rest
to the company. So if your goal is to raise the living
standards of Mexican workers, this is a lousy way to do it.
Its interesting to see how the same phenomenon is going
on in the copyright industry, the same general idea. In
the name of these workers who certainly deserve something, you
propose measures that give them a tiny bit and really mainly
prop up the power of corporations to control our lives.
If youre trying to replace a very good system, you have
to work very hard to come up with a better alternative.
If you know that the present system is lousy, its not
so hard to find a better alternative; the standard of comparison
today is very low. We must always remember that when we
consider issues of copyright policy.
So I think
Ive said most of what I want to say. Id like
to mention that tomorrow is Phone-In Sick Day in Canada.
Tomorrow is the beginning of a summit to finish negotiating
the free trade area of the Americas to try to extend corporate
power throughout additional countries, and a big protest is
being planned for Quebec. Weve seen extreme methods
being used to smash this protest. A lot of Americans are
being blocked from entering Canada through the border that theyre
supposed to be allowed to enter through at any time. On
the flimsiest of excuses, a wall has been built around the center
of Quebec to be used as a fortress to keep protesters out.
Weve seen a large number of different dirty tricks used
against public protest against these treaties. So whatever
democracy remains to us after government powers have been taken
away from democratically elected governors and given to businesses
and to unelected international bodies, whatever is left after
that may not survive the suppression of public protest against
it.
Ive dedicated 17 years of my life to working on free software
and allied issues. I didnt do this because I think
its the most important political issue in the world.
I did it because it was the area where I saw I had to use my
skills to do a lot of good. But whats happened is
that the general issues of politics have evolved, and the biggest
political issue in the world today is resisting the tendency
to give business power over the public and governments.
I see free software and the allied questions for other kinds
of information that Ive been discussing today as one part
of that major issue. So Ive indirectly found myself
working on that issue. I hope I contribute something to
the effort.
THORBURN: Well turn to the audience
for questions and comments in a moment. But let me offer
a brief general response. It seems to me that the strongest
and most important practical guidance that Stallman offers us
has two key elements. One is the recognition that
old assumptions about copyright, old usages of copyright are
inappropriate; they are challenged or undermined by the advent
of the computer and computer networks. That may be obvious,
but it is essential.
Second is the recognition that the digital era requires us to
reconsider how we distinguish and weigh forms of intellectual
and creative labor. Stallman is surely right that certain
kinds of intellectual enterprises justify more copyright protection
than others. Trying to identify systematically these different
kinds or levels of copyright protection seems to me a
valuable way to engage with the problems for intellectual work
posed by the advent of the computer.
But I think I detect another theme that lies beneath what Stallman
has been saying and that isnt really directly about computers
at all, but more broadly about questions of democratic authority
and the power that government and corporations increasingly
exercise over our lives. This populist and anti-corporate
side to Stallmans discourse is nourishing but also reductive,
potentially simplifying. And it is also perhaps overly
idealistic. For example, how would a
a novelist or a poet or a songwriter or a musician or the author
of an academic textbook survive in this brave new world where
people are encouraged but not required to pay authors.
In other words, it seems to me, the gap between existing practice
and the visionary possibilities Stallman speculates
about is still immensely wide.
So Ill conclude by asking if Stallman would like to expand
a bit on certain aspects of his talk and, specifically, whether
he has further thoughts about the way in which what well
call traditional creators would be protected under
his copyright system.STALLMAN: First of all, I have to
point out that we shouldnt use the term protection
to describe what copyright does. Copyright restricts people.
The term protection is a propaganda term of the
copyright-owning businesses. The term protection
means stopping something from being somehow destroyed.
Well, I dont think a song is destroyed if there are more
copies of it being played more. I dont think that
a novel is destroyed if more people are reading copies of it,
either. So I wont use that word. I think it
leads people to identify with the wrong party.
Also, its a very bad idea to think about intellectual
property for two reasons: First, it prejudges the most
fundamental question in the area which is: How should
these things be treated and should they be treated as a kind
of property? To use the term intellectual property
to describe the area is to presuppose the answer is yes,
that thats the way to treat things, not some other way.
Second, it encourages over-generalization. Intellectual
property is a catch-all for several different legal systems
with independent origins such as, copyrights, patents, trademarks,
trade secrets and some other things as well. They are
almost completely different; they have nothing in common.
But people who hear the term intellectual property
are led to a false picture where they imagine that theres
a general principle of intellectual property that was applied
to specific areas, so they assume that these various areas of
the law are similar. This leads not only to confused thinking
about what is right to do, it leads people to fail to understand
what the law actually says because they suppose that the copyright
law and patent law and trademark law are similar, when, in fact,
they are totally different.
So if you want to encourage careful thinking and clear understanding
of what the law says, avoid the term intellectual property.
Talk about copyrights. Or talk about patents. Or
talk about trademarks or whichever subject you want to talk
about. But dont talk about intellectual property.
Opinion about intellectual property almost has to be a foolish
one. I dont have an opinion about intellectual property.
I have opinions about copyrights and patents and trademarks,
and theyre different. I came to them through different
thought processes because those systems of law are totally different.
Anyway,
I made that digression, but its terribly important.
So let me now get to the point. Of course, we cant
see now how well it would work, whether it would work to ask
people to pay money voluntarily to the authors and musicians
they love. One thing thats obvious is that how well
such a system would work is proportional to the number of people
who are participating in the network, and that number, we know,
is going to increase by an order of magnitude over a number
of years. If we tried it today, it might fail, and that
wouldnt prove anything because with ten times as many
people participating, it might work.
The other thing is, we do not have this digital cash payment
system; so we cant really try it today. You could
try to do something a little bit like it. There are services
you can sign up for where you can pay money to someone
things like Pay Pal. But before you can pay anyone through
Pay Pal, you have to go through a lot of rigmarole and give
them personal information about you, and they collect records
of whom you pay. Can you trust them not to misuse that?
So the dollar might not discourage you, but the trouble it takes
to pay might discourage you. The whole idea of this is
that it should be as easy as falling off a log to pay when you
get the urge, so that theres nothing to discourage you
except the actual amount of money. And if thats
small enough, why should it discourage you. We know, though,
that fans can really love musicians, and we know that encouraging
fans to copy and re-distribute the music has been done by some
bands that were, and are, quite successful like the Grateful
Dead. They didnt have any trouble making a
living from their music because they encouraged fans to tape
it and copy the tapes. They didnt even lose their
record sales.
We are gradually moving from the age of the printing press to
the age of the computer network, but its not happening
in a day. People are still buying lots of records, and
that will probably continue for many years maybe forever.
As long as that continues, simply having copyrights that still
apply to commercial sales of records ought to do about as good
a job of supporting musicians as it does today. Of course,
thats not very good, but, at least, it wont get
any worse.
DISCUSSION:
QUESTION: [A comment and and question about free
downloading and about Stephen Kings attempt to market
one of his novels serially over the web.]
STALLMAN: Yes, its interesting to know what
he did and what happened. When I first heard about that,
I was elated. I thought, maybe he was taking a step towards
a world that is not based on trying to maintain an iron grip
on the public. Then I saw that he had actually written
to ask people to pay. To explain what he did, he was publishing
a novel as a serial, by installments, and he said, If
I get enough money, Ill release more. But
the request he wrote was hardly a request. It brow-beat
the reader. It said, If you dont pay, then
youre evil. And if there are too many of you who
are evil, then Im just going to stop writing this.
Well, clearly, thats not the way to make the public feel
like sending you money. Youve got to make them love
you, not fear you.
SPEAKER: The details were that he required a certain
percentage I dont know the exact percentage, around
90% sounds correct of people to send a certain amount
of money, which, I believe, was a dollar or two dollars, or
somewhere in that order of magnitude. You had to type
in your name and your e-mail address and some other information
to get to download it and if that percentage of people was not
reached after the first chapter, he said that he would not release
another chapter. It was very antagonistic to the public
downloading it.QUESTION: Isnt the scheme where theres
no copyright but people are asked to make voluntary donations
open to abuse by people plagiarizing?
STALLMAN: No. Thats not what I proposed.
Remember, Im proposing that there should be copyright
covering commercial distribution and permitting only verbatim
re-distribution non-commercially. So anyone who modified
it to put in a pointer to his website, instead of a pointer
to the real authors website, would still be infringing
the copyright and could be sued exactly as he could be sued
today.QUESTION: I see. So youre still imagining
a world in which there is copyright?
STALLMAN: Yes. As Ive said, for those
kinds of works. Im not saying that everything should
be permitted. Im proposing to reduce copyright powers,
not abolish them.
THORBURN: I guess one question that occurred to me
while you were speaking, Richard, and, again, now when youre
responding here to this question is why you dont consider
the ways in which the computer, itself, eliminates the middle
men completely in the way that Stephen King refused to
do and might establish a personal relationship.
STALLMAN: Well, they can and, in fact, this voluntary
donation is one
THORBURN: You think of that as not involving going
through a publisher at all?
STALLMAN: Absolutely not. I hope it wont,
you see, because the publishers exploit the authors terribly.
When you ask the publishers representatives about this,
they say, Well, yes, if an author or if a band doesnt
want to go through us, they shouldnt be legally required
to go through us. But, in fact, theyre doing
their utmost to set it up so that will not be feasible.
For instance, theyre proposing restricted copying media
formats and in order to publish in these formats, youll
have to go through the big publishers because they wont
tell anyone else how to do it. So theyre hoping
for a world where the players will play these formats, and in
order to get anything that you can play on those players, itll
have to come through the publishers. So, in fact, while
theres no law against an author or a musician publishing
directly, it wont be feasible. Theres also
the lure of maybe hitting it rich. They say, Well
publicize you and maybe youll hit it as rich as the Beatles.
Take your pick of some very successful group and, of course,
only a tiny fraction of musicians are going to have that happen.
But they may be drawn by that into signing contracts that will
lock them down forever.
Publishers tend to be very bad at respecting their contracts
with authors. For instance, book contracts typically have
said that if a book goes out of print, the rights revert to
the author, and publishers have generally not been very good
about living up to that clause. They often have to be
forced. Well, what theyre starting to do now is
use electronic publication as an excuse to say that its
never going out of print; so they never have to give the rights
back. Their idea is, when the author has no clout, get
him to sign up and from then on, he has no power; its
only the publisher that has the power.
QUESTION:
Would it be good to have free licenses for various kinds of
works that protect for every user the freedom to copy them in
whatever is the appropriate way for that kind of work?
STALLMAN: Well, people are working on this. But
for non-functional works, one thing doesnt substitute
for another. Lets look at a functional kind of work,
say, a word processor. Well, if somebody makes a free
word processor, you can use that; you dont need the non-free
word processors. But I wouldnt say that one free
song substitutes for all the non-free songs or that a one free
novel substitutes for all the non-free novels. For those
kinds of works, its different. So what I think
we simply have to do is to recognize that these laws do not
deserve to be respected. Its not wrong to share
with your neighbor, and if anyone tries to tell you that you
cannot share with your neighbor, you should not listen to him.
QUESTION: With regard to the functional works,
how do you, in your own thinking, balance out the need for abolishing
the copyright with the need for economic incentives in order
to have these functional works developed?
STALLMAN: Well, what we see is, first of all, that
this economic incentive is a lot less necessary than people
have been supposing. Look at the free software movement
where we have over 100,000 part-time volunteers developing free
software. We also see that there are other ways to raise
money for this which are not based on stopping the public from
copying and modifying these works. Thats the interesting
lesson of the free software movement. Aside from the fact
that it gives you a way you can use a computer and keep your
freedom to share and cooperate with other people, it also shows
us that this negative assumption that people would never do
these things unless they are given special powers to force people
to pay them is simply wrong. A lot of people will do these
things. Then if you look at, say, the writing of monographs
which serve as textbooks in many fields of science except for
the ones that are very basic, the authors are not making money
out of that. We now have a free encyclopedia project which
is, in fact, a commercial-free encyclopedia project, and its
making progress. We had a project for a GNU encyclopedia
but we merged it into the commercial project when they adopted
our license. In January, they switched to the GNU-free
documentation license for all the articles in their encyclopedia.
So we said, Well, lets join forces with them and
urge people to contribute to them. Its called
Nupedia, and you can find a link to it at http://
www.gnu.org/encyclopedia. So here weve extended
the community development of a free base of useful knowledge
from software to encyclopedia. Im pretty confident
now that in all these areas of functional work, we dont
need that economic incentive to the point where we have to mess
up the use of these works.
THORBURN: Well, what about the other two categories.
For the other two classes of work, I dont know.
I dont know whether people will write some day novels
without worrying about whether they make money from it.
In a post-scarcity society, I guess they would. Maybe
what we need to do in order to reach the post-scarcity society
is to get rid of the corporate control over the economy and
the laws. So, in effect, its a chicken-or-the-egg
problem, you know. Which do we do first? How do
we get the world where people dont have to desperately
get money except by removing the control by business?
And how can we remove the control by business except --
Anyway, I dont know, but thats why Im trying
to propose first a compromise copyright system and, second,
the voluntary payment supported by a compromise copyright system
as a way to provide a revenue stream to the people who write
those works.
QUESTION: How would you really expect to implement
this compromise copyright system under the chokehold of corporate
interests on American politicians due to their campaign-finance
system?
STALLMAN: It beats me. I wish I knew.
Its a terribly hard problem. If I knew how to solve
that problem, I would solve it and nothing in the world could
make me prouder.
QUESTION: How do you fight the corporate control?
Because when you look at these sums of money going into corporate
lobbying in the court case, it is tremendous. I think
the DeCSS case that youre talking about is costing something
like a million-and-a-half dollars on the defense side.
Lord knows what its costing on the corporate side.
Do you have any idea how to deal with these huge sums of money?
STALLMAN: I have a suggestion. If I were
to suggest totally boycotting movies, I think people would ignore
that suggestion. They might consider it too radical.
So I would like to make a slightly different suggestion which
comes to almost the same thing in the end, and that is, dont
go to a movie unless you have some substantial reason to think
its good. Now this will lead in practice to almost
the same result as a total boycott of Hollywood movies.
In extension, its almost the same but, in intention, its
very different. Now Ive noticed that many people
go to movies for reasons that have nothing to do with whether
they think the movies are good. So if you change that,
if you only go to a movie when you have some substantial reason
to think its good, youll take away a lot of their
money.
THORBURN: One way to understand all of this discourse
today, I think, is to recognize that whenever radical,
potentially transforming technologies appear in society, theres
a struggle over who controls them. We today are
repeating what has happened in the past. So from this
angle, there may not be a reason for despair, or even pessimism,
about what may occur in the longer run. But, in the shorter
term, struggles over the control of text and images, over all
forms of information are likely to be painful and extensive.
For example, as a teacher of media, my access to images has
been restricted in recent years in a way that had never been
in place before. If I write an essay in which I want to
use still images, even from films, they are much harder to get
permission to use, and the prices charged to use those still
images are much higher even when I make arguments about
intellectual inquiry and the the legal category of fair
use. So I think, in this moment of extended transformation,
the longer-term prospects may, in fact, not be as disturbing
as whats happening in the shorter term. But in any
case, we need to understand the whole of our contemporary experience
as a renewed version of a struggle over the control of technological
resources that is a recurring principle of Western society.
Its also essential to understand that the history of older
technologies is itself a complicated matter. The impact
of the printing press in Spain, for example, is radically different
from its impact in England or in France.
QUESTION: One of the things that bothers me when
I hear discussions of copyright is that often they start off
with, We want a 180-degree change. We want to do
away with any sorts of control. It seems to me that
part of what lay under the three categories that were suggested
is an acknowledgement that there is some wisdom to copyright.
Some of the critics of the way copyright is going now believe
that, in fact, it ought to be backed up and function much more
like patent and trademarks in terms of its duration. I
wonder if our speaker would comment on that as a strategy.
STALLMAN: I agree that shortening the time span
of copyright is a good idea. There is absolutely no need
in terms of encouraging publication for a possibility of copyrights
lasting as much as 150 years, which, in some cases, it can under
present law. Now the companies were saying that a 75-year
copyright on a work made for hire was not long enough to make
possible the production of their works. Id like
to challenge those companies to present projected balance sheets
for 75 years from now to back up that contention. What
they really wanted was just to be able to extend the copyrights
on the old works, so that they can continue restricting the
use of them. But how you can encourage greater production
of works in the 1920s by extending copyright today escapes me,
unless they have a time machine somewhere. Of course,
in one of their movies, they had a time machine. So maybe
thats what affected their thinking.
QUESTION: Have you given thought to extending the
concept of fair use, and are there any nuances there
that you might care to lay out for us?
STALLMAN: Well, the idea of giving everyone permission
for non-commercial verbatim copying of two kinds of works, certainly,
may be thought of as extending what fair use is. Its
bigger than whats fair use currently. If your idea is
that the public trades away certain freedoms to get more progress,
then you can draw the line at various, different places.
Which freedoms does the public trade away and which freedoms
does the public keep?
QUESTION: To extend the conversation for just a
moment, in certain entertainment fields, we have the concept
of a public presentation. So, for example, copyright does
not prevent us from singing Christmas carols seasonally but
it prevents the public performance. And Im wondering
if it might be useful to think about instead of expanding fair
use to unlimited, non-commercial, verbatim copying, to something
less than that but more than the present concept of fair use.
STALLMAN: I used to think that that might be enough,
and then Napster convinced me otherwise because Napster is used
by its users for non-commercial, verbatim re-distribution.
The Napster server, itself, is a commercial activity but the
people who are actually putting things up are doing so non-commercially,
and they could have done so on their websites just as easily.
The tremendous excitement about, interest in, and use of Napster
shows that thats very useful. So Im convinced
now that people should have the right to public, non-commercially
redistributed, verbatim copies of everything.
QUESTION: One analogy that was recently suggested
to me for the whole Napster question was the analogy of the
public library. I suppose some of you who have heard the
Napster arguments have heard this analogy. Im wondering
if you would comment on it. The defenders of people who
say Napster should continue and there shouldnt be restrictions
on it sometimes say something like this: When folks go
into the public library and borrow a book, theyre not
paying for it, and it can be borrowed dozens of times, hundreds
of time, without any additional payment. Why is Napster
any different?
STALLMAN: Well, its not exactly the same.
But it should be pointed out that the publishers want to transform
public libraries into pay-per-use, retail outlets. So
theyre against public libraries.
QUESTION: Can these ideas about copyright suggest
any ideas for certain issues about patent law such as making
cheap, generic drugs for use in Africa?
STALLMAN: No, theres absolutely no similarity.
The issues of patents are totally different from the issues
of copyrights. The idea that they have something to do
with each other is one of the unfortunate consequences of using
the term intellectual property and encouraging people
to try to lump these issues together because, as youve
heard, Ive been talking about issues in which the price
of a copy is not the crucial thing. But whats the
crucial issue about making AIDS drugs for Africa? Its
the price, nothing but the price.
Now the issue Ive been talking about arises because digital
information technology gives every user the ability to make
copies. Well, theres nothing giving us all the ability
to make copies of medicines. I dont have the ability
to copy some medicine that Ive got. In fact, nobody
does; thats not how theyre made. Those medicines
can only be made in expensive factories and they are made in
expensive centralized factories, whether theyre generic
drugs or imported from the U.S. Either way, theyre
going to be made in a small number of factories, and the issues
are simply how much do they cost and are they available at a
price that people in Africa can afford.
So thats a tremendously important issue, but its
a totally different issue. Theres just one area
where an issue arises with patents that is actually similar
to these issues of freedom to copy, and that is in the area
of agriculture. Because there are certain patented things
that can be copies, more or less namely, living things.
They copy themselves when they reproduce. Its not
necessarily exact copying; they re-shuffle the genes.
But the fact is, farmers for millennia have been making use
of this capacity of the living things they grow to copy themselves.
Farming is, basically, copying the things that you grew and
you keep copying them every year. When plant and animal
varieties get patented, when genes are patented and used in
them, the result is that farmers are being prohibited from doing
this.
There is a farmer in Canada who had a patented variety growing
on his field and he said, I didnt do that deliberately.
The pollen blew, and those genes got into my stock of plants.
And he was told that that doesnt matter; he has to destroy
them anyway. It was an extreme example of how much government
can side with a monopolist.
So I believe
that, following the same principles that I apply to copying
things on your computer, farmers should have an unquestioned
right to save their seeds and breed their livestock. Maybe
you could have patents covering seed companies, but they shouldnt
cover farmers.
QUESTION: Theres more to making a model successful
than just the licensing. Can you speak to that?
STALLMAN: Absolutely. Well, you know, I dont
know the answers. But part of what I believe is crucial
for developing free, functional information is idealism.
People have to recognize that its important for this information
to be free, that when the information is free, you can make
full use of it. When its restricted, you cant.
You have to recognize that the non-free information is an attempt
to divide people and keep them helpless and keep them down.
Then they can get the idea, Lets work together to
produce the information we want to use, so that its not
under the control of some powerful person who can dictate to
us what we can do.
This tremendously boosts it. But I dont know how
much it will work in various different areas, but I think that
in the area of education, when youre looking for textbooks,
I think I see a way it can be done. There are a lot of
teachers in the world, teachers who are not at prestigious universities
maybe theyre in high-school; maybe theyre
in college where they dont write and publish a
lot of things and theres not a tremendous demand for them.
But a lot of them are smart. A lot of them know their
subjects well and they could write textbooks about lots of subjects
and share them with the world and receive a tremendous amount
of appreciation from the people who will have learned from them.
QUESTION: Thats what I proposed. But
the funny thing is, I do know the history of education.
Thats what I do educational, electronic media projects.
I couldnt find an example. Do you know of one?
STALLMAN: No, I dont. I started proposing
this free encyclopedia and learning resource a couple of years
ago, and I thought it would probably take a decade to get things
rolling. Now we already have an encyclopedia that is rolling.
So things are going faster than I hoped. I think whats
needed is for a few people to start writing some free textbooks.
Write one about whatever is your favorite subject or write a
fraction of one. Write a few chapters of one and challenge
other people to write the rest.
QUESTION: Actually what I was looking for is something
even more than that. Whats important in your kind
of structure is somebody that creates an infrastructure to which
everybody else can contribute. There isnt a K through
12 infrastructure out there in any place for a contribution
for materials. I can get information from lots of places but
its not released under free licenses, so I cant
use it to make a free textbook.
STALLMAN: Actually, copyright doesnt cover
the facts. It only covers the way its written.
So you can learn a field from anywhere and then write a textbook,
and you can make that textbook free, if you want.
QUESTION: But I cant write by myself all
the textbooks that a student needs going through school.
STALLMAN: Well, its true. And I didnt
write a whole, free operating system, either. I wrote
some pieces and invited other people to join me by writing other
pieces. So I set an example. I said, Im
going in this direction. Join me and well get there.
And enough people joined in that we got there. So if you
think in terms of, how am I going to get this whole gigantic
job done, it can be daunting. So the point is, dont
look at it that way. Think in terms of taking a step and
realizing that after youve taken a step, other people
will take more steps and, together, it will get the job done
eventually.
Assuming that humanity doesnt wipe itself out, the work
we do today to produce the free educational infrastructure,
the free learning resource for the world, that will be useful
for as long as humanity exists. If it takes 20 years to
get it done, so what? So dont think in terms of
the size of the whole job. Think in terms of the piece
that youre going to do. That will show people it
can be done, and so others will do other pieces.
Verbatim copying and distribution of this entire article are
permitted in any medium provided this notice is preserved.