|
||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||
Setting Appropriate Standards explores the different agendas of the various actors involved in service provision. The Problems Involved in Standards examines the importance of distinguishing between what ought to be and what can be achieved when setting standards. Projects in which standards feature: Lusaka Upgrading Project, Kampung Improvement Program, |
||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||
Setting Appropriate Infrastructure Standards |
||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||
Should poor countries permit higher risks of failure than rich ones? The answer may be yes, because the rich ones have used abundant resources to reduce risks to extremely low levels. Why not? In those countries, water bills for consumers are trivial. In developing countries, this may not be so. Anyway, the rich country is fully served, so there is no trade-off. In poor countries risk is lowered in one locality at the cost of fully exposing another. Thus the terms of the problem of research on uncertainty is to simply induce the understanding that uncertainties are in some ways contemplatable, rather than being detached phenomena that may be dealt with only by maximizing the hedge against them. (p 148) |
||||||||||||
Different Agendas that All Lead to Unnecessarily High Standards Standards are not really a technology problem, but rather an institutional problem that can double the cost of services. (Gakenheimer 133) Often, infrastructure projects are designed with excessively high standards - excessively large pipes, unnecessarily high quality material in pipe manufacture - and thus they reach fewer people with given project funds. The various parties involved are a series of mutually independent domestic actors, each pursuing an independent agenda, but ending up sustaining the same unfortunate tendency: increasingly high and unrealistic standards for urban infrastructure that make poor use of very limited national resources. (p 142) The Actors and Their Agendas:
Steps Toward a Solution Four steps are proposed toward a solution:
|
||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||
The Problem of Standards |
||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||
The most common objection to changes in public policy which would increase the user's control in housing at the expense of central institutions is that standards would be lowered as a result. The standards the objectors have in mind, however, are not something which can be achieved with available resources but, rather, represent the objector's own notion of what housing ought to be. The fact that the enforcement of unrealistic standards (unilaterally defined as the minimum acceptable) serves only to worsen the housing conditions for the poor raises the basic issue in housing that of its meaning and value for people. The emotions which this universal aspect of housing problems stirs up prove its close association with deep human and cultural values. The minimum standards for housing, building, and planning to which I refer are those which specify what should be built, and very often, they go a long way to determining how the subdivision, dwelling, or ancillary equipment should be built as well. Almost all official codes, in the wealthiest and poorest countries alike, require that a building plot be fully equipped with modern utilities, and even with paved streets and sidewalks, before it may be sold to a would-be home builder. Even then the buyer cannot occupy his house until it is completed, at least to a minimum standard, which usually means separate bedrooms, and equipped bathroom, and a kitchen separated from the living area. An investment of this kind demands a mortgage loan, and if the property cannot be occupied until it is finished, or at least certified as habitable, it is extremely difficult for the owner to build it himself he is virtually obliged to employ a general contractor or, more likely, to buy a ready-made unit in a speculative development or in a publicly sponsored project. Subdivision codes of the kind and standard described above were instituted in Lima in 1915; these were followed in 1935 by conventional modern minimum standards for dwelling units. It is easy to anticipate the problems created by regulations like these in cities with a large and rapidly growing low-income populations such as Lima (which is more typical of the contemporary world than the cities of Europe and North America). Insofar as such standards are enforceable, they price the great majority of would-be home builders out of the market, and even without the added discouragement of rent freezes, they inhibit legitimate, inspected, taxable private investments in low-income housing, whether for rent or for sale. Hence it is not surprising to find that two-thirds of all new dwellings built in Lima since the early 1940s and over 90 percent in the poorer provincial city of Arequipa were put up by squatters or buyers of lots in clandestine subdivisions. Neither is it surprising to observe that since it became illegal to build tenements which the mass of the people can afford, those remaining have become grossly overcrowded while illegal shanty towns have proliferated. (I refer to conglomerations of tented shacks that must be distinguished from the pueblos jóvenes and the urbanizaciones populares consisting of owner-built dwellings of far superior standards.) In fact, housing conditions for the poorest fifth or quarter of Limas population are far worse now than they were in the 1890s, and demand substantially higher proportions of personal income to boot. Although building codes have made great contributions to human welfare in countries with high per capita incomes, their rigidity often contributes to a shortage of safe and sanitary housing. In many cities of the U.S., for example, owner-building is virtually prohibited, and in many more the administration of building codes is an important factor in the precipitate abandonment of older housing, so badly needed by the urban poor. The disastrous abandonment rate of structurally sound but obsolescent housing which each year in New York City alone currently amounts to the stock for a fair-sized town is in part due to housing codes and their administration. A license has to be obtained in order to replace a defective roof, for example. But if the building is obsolescent, this may not be granted unless the entire building is brought up to standard and by licensed builders. Therefore, because the owner or a willing tenant is forbidden to do a job he would have been quite able to do, and very cheaply, an entire building is lost, thus accelerating the decay of the neighborhood. This begins to suggest that minimum specification standards are frequently, if not generally, counterproductive under at least two sets of conditions. First, when there is a significant gap between levels of investment they require and the effective demand; and second, when that gap cannot be closed with subsidies, whether through lack of financial resources or lack of will on the governments part. If governments cannot, or will not, make up the difference between what housing laws require and what the effective demand can purchase, then why do they create these problems? Why is the common sense solution of allowing and encouraging people to make the best use of what they have treated as subversive nonsense by the technocratic and bureaucratic authorities? Why do these authorities and the institutions they control refuse to let people live and move between the extremes of neglected, dangerous slums and residences suitable for middle-class Joneses? Why, in other words, are the problems so universally defined in terms of what people ought to have (in the view of the problem-staters) instead of in realistic terms of what people could have? |
||||||||||||
|